- The emergence of dominant design can allow for the economies of scope and scale, making production more efficient (Utterback and Abernathy 1975) – a social good.
- The emergence of a dominant design can lock in a particular technological path. This could potentially be sub-optimal (e.g. QWERTY keyboard), or it could guarantee a monopoly with high prices (e.g. iPod) – both social bads.
Studying the emergence of dominant designs in science or business is hard, because typically only small numbers of choices are made (one animal model chosen by a scientist, one MP3 player released by a company). This makes econometric identification difficult because sample sizes are too small to disentangle other effects (e.g. the observation of an iPod’s dominance could be due to any of the unique features of Apple). Additionally, these adoption patterns are usually path-specific, with scientists or companies making long-term sets of decisions that interlink their choices. This makes the establishment of causality difficult.
Synthetic Biology, the science of writing DNA sequences to get new biologic functions, provides a promising empirical setting to study this question for several reasons:
- Technological innovations in synthetic biology are embodied in their DNA sequences (which are often both content and process). Thus it is comparatively easy to see the usage and evolution of designs using databases of DNA parts (e.g. BioBrick’s Registry of Standard Biological Parts).
- Unlike many other areas in science / business, many of the parts from Synthetic Biology can be understood to be complements or substitutes for one another by looking at their DNA sequences, and seeing which ones are designed to be used together.
- The technology underlying Synthetic Biology is growing enormously fast (much faster than Moore’s Law). As such, many new designs and standards are being set. This large sample size will help disentangle the importance of other competing factors in the adoption of dominant designs.